E LAW - MURDOCH UNIVERSITY ELECTRONIC JOURNAL OF LAW VOLUME 1 NUMBER 4 (DECEMBER 1994) Copyright E Law and/or authors Review of Western Australian State Taxes 1994 Chapter 12 STAMP DUTY AND FINANCIAL TAXES IN THE 21ST CENTURY Introduction Stamp Duties Financial Institutions and Debits Tax A Fresh Proposal - A Financial Institution Transaction Tax (The `FIT' Tax) Proposals for the Future of Financial Taxes Bibliography INTRODUCTION Part one of this chapter examines the operation of the Stamp Act 1921 (WA). It is suggested that although comprehensive reforms to the Act have been submitted to government, the fact these have not been acted upon is indicative of current governmental tax policy which is primarily concerned with revenue raised, as opposed to scrutinising the patchwork of provisions which are often inadequate for revenue collection, and fail to satisfy the criteria for a `good' tax.[1] It is suggested that the Act be rewritten and that many of the proposed reforms be included.In part two, Financial Institutions Duty and Debit Tax are re-examined and a new tax regime is suggested that consolidates the two taxes. The review then examines Financial Taxes in the light of changing technology in the Banking Industry. STAMP DUTIES Stamp Duty is a State or Territory tax imposed on the value of certain transactions as specified within the Act and applied at either a fixed, or `ad valorem' rate.[2] It is generally recognised to be solely for the benefit of raising State taxes.[3]The 1993 Review of Western Australian State Taxes looked at several items from the Second Schedule of the Stamp Act 1921 in the context of public finance criteria (equity, simplicity and efficiency). It found inter alia that Part IVA of the Act, which provides for sales and purchases of Marketable Securities by Brokers, is extremely narrowly based in its taxing application and therefore offends the principle of equity.[4] On this basis it was suggested that the stamp duty on transfers be abolished and replaced by increasing the Financial Institutions Duty and Debits Tax base.[5] Moreover, it was also suggested that cheque duty contributes little by way of revenue, discriminates against cheque users and, because Debits tax also applies to the cheques, amounts to "double taxation".[6] This reiterated the conclusions of the Reform of the Stamp Act Western Australian Final Report, (hereafter `The Final Report'), which received submissions on this aspect of the Act, it was recommended that the duty be abolished and revenue replaced by either broadening the Debits base or increasing the Financial Institutions Duty rate.[7]The Final Report proposal, along with other recommendations aimed at furthering the needs of both Government and commercial practice, was submitted to Treasury in 1992 for consideration by Government. To date, whether through the subsequent change of Government, differing political prioritising, or inertia, no major reforms have been enacted. The fact that no such rationalisation of the Act has taken place can be seen as an indication that Government assumes a pragmatic overview in regard to this method of revenue raising. They likely perceive the amount raised as satisfactory[8] and the method as `tried and true' from a point of political acceptability, therefore suggestions which could upset the present taxing balance by increasing another tax, could be seen as politically unpalatable.[9]On this basis, reform in the areas suggested in the Final Report are unlikely to occur in the near future. If any major amendments do occur it will probably only be as a result of specific practical circumstances which cannot be ignored. Technology and Amendments to Parts IVA and IVB of the Stamp Act A case in point are the future amendments to Parts IVA - Sales and Purchases of Marketable Securities by Brokers, and Part IVBA - Miscellaneous Provisions In Respect of Marketable Securities. These sections of the Act essentially provide the requirements to be adhered to when recording share sales, purchases, transfers and the returns to be remitted to The Commissioner of State Taxation. As of the first of July 1994 the Australian Stock Exchange (ASX) will implement CHESS, the Clearing House and Electronic Subregister System, a new electronic system providing for the register and transfer of securities. It is said to bring about significant cost savings and increased efficiency to the ASX.[10] Concomitant to this will be the introduction in May 1994 of the new Bill into Parliament incorporating amendments to make the Stamp Act compatible with electronic share transfer and enable the remittance of duty on electronic transactions to be forwarded by disc.[11]This is likely the beginning of another `modernising' of the Stamp Act 1921, making it electronic transaction based, while still providing for instrument type transactions. It is possible that in the future, in conjunction with like technology being implemented into the Department of Land Administration, Financial Institutions will be able to record mortgages electronically and remit Stamp Duty returns in a similar way. However, in the haste to accommodate new technology it is important not to lose sight of other provisions within the Act which offend the criteria for a "good" tax. Practical Operation of Section 27(1) of the Stamp Act Section 27(1) of the Act states, generally, that if Stamp Duty is not paid on a dutiable instrument then it cannot be used in evidence in a civil case by either party to the transaction. Many Western Australian cases illustrate the inequity of this provision.[12] To use sale of land as an example,[13] the Act does not differentiate between a purchaser with the liability to pay the duty who wants to plead or give the contract in evidence, and the vendor. In the case of the purchaser, the Act can be said to operate fairly in the circumstances, but when it is a vendor who wants to rely on the contract in court, they can be penalised unfairly by the section.[14]The purpose of this provision was to protect Government revenue. In the past it was `self-policing' in that parties to transactions ignored `voluntary' stamping at the peril of not being able to use their contract in court.[15] Since 1979 legislation has enabled the imposition of fines for non-compliance, made failure to pay an offence and given the Commissioner power to sue for unpaid stamp duty.[16] Besides the unfair operation of the Act towards the `innocent' party who may not want, nor have the means, to chance paying the duty and then attempting to recover it from the purchaser whose liability it was - it is suggested that the provision, as it stands, to some extent defeats revenue raising. At present, where a non-liable party wishes to enforce a transaction but fails for want of contractual evidence because of unpaid duty, no revenue is received. Whereas, if the unstamped instrument could be admitted into court and found enforceable, then its lack of stamping in breach of s.39 could be highlighted with the possibility that stamping could also be enforced, and revenue received. In 1991, a proposal for reform of s.27 was put to Government by the Commissioner of State Taxation.[17] It was in line with similar provisions in the New South Wales and Tasmanian Stamp Acts[18] whereby an `innocent' party can inform the Commissioner of State Taxation of the name of the person liable for the duty, and lodge either the instrument or a copy with the Commissioner for assessment before then being able to use it in evidence. Unfortunately, such an amendment is yet to be enacted. Rulings From the perspective of business, one way of streamlining the operation of the Act is through a comprehensive system of rulings. These are essentially information provided by the Stamp Office detailing the Commissioner's interpretation of certain provisions and schedules within the Act. The New South Wales Office of State Revenue has issued approximately two hundred rulings, Victoria, less, and Western Australia, nine. The policy of the Department of State Taxation in Western Australia amounts to a belief that the release of rulings generally, will promote tax evasion in the area under discussion. An Overview of the Act In conclusion, it seems the Stamp Act is in grave danger of remaining a complex patchwork of past and future amendments. It is suggested that it is time to re-write the Act, with consideration given to problems identified in past reform proposals. With both large and small, more specific provisions (s.27) being given equal priority. If at all possible it should be written in such a manner as to accommodate future technological changes. Finally, the re-written Act should be as readable and accessible to the lay person as can be achieved, after all a `good' tax is one that is understandable to the taxpayer.[19] FINANCIAL INSTITUTIONS DUTY AND DEBITS TAX Structure of FID and Debits Tax Financial Institutions Duty is levied in Western Australia under the Financial Institutions Duty Act 1983 (`the FID Act') which came into operation on 1 January 1984. FID is imposed at the low rate of 0.06% upon the receipts (ie. deposits to) of registered financial institutions.[20] FID of 0.06% is also imposed under s.12 of the FID Act on depositors transacting with unregistered Financial Institutions.[21] A concessional FID of 0.04% or 0.05% applies under section 11 of the FID Act to the short term money market dealings of short term dealers. Under the FID Act, the financial institutions and the short term dealers are made liable for the duty (s.10 and s.11), and also must furnish monthly returns to the State tax department (s.23 and s.27). In total, FID collected in Western Australia represents between 6-7% of total taxation revenue. In the financial year ending 30 June 1993, FID collected was $96 million or 6.97% of total taxation receipts. Debits tax receipts in the same period were $41 million or 2.97%.[22]The power to impose a tax on debits was transferred from the Commonwealth to the States from 1 January 1991. Debits tax has been levied in Western Australia from that date under the Debits Tax Act 1990 (`the Debits Act') and the Debits Tax Assessment Act 1990 (`the Act'). This tax only applies to debits or withdrawals not less than $1, from accounts as defined in s.3(1) of the Act. This definition effectively limits the tax to cheque rather than saving accounts.[23] The rates on which the tax is calculated are set out in Schedule 1 of the Debits Act. As pointed out by last year's review [24] this tax rate is regressive as the larger the withdrawal, the smaller the proportion of attendant tax. The 1993 Review of FID and Debits Tax - Briefly stated Last year's tax policy elective found FID and Debits tax satisfactorily simple. They are taxes that are easy to understand, calculate and collect. There are only a few collection points as financial institutions and short term dealers collect the tax on behalf of the State (thereby also rendering the tax easy to regulate). FID was also found to be efficient or economically neutral in impact as it was broad based and imposed at a rate low enough to discourage avoidance. FID was also equitable due largely to its broad based nature. Debits tax, on the other hand, was inefficient in that it encouraged the use of savings rather than cheque accounts to avoid the tax, it was horizontally inequitable due to the same cheque/savings account demarcation and vertically inequitable due to the regressive rate of the tax. The following is a summary of the recommendations which flowed from that analysis: - that uniformity of the FID and Debit tax regimes between all States be pursued; - that all exemptions to FID and Debits tax based on solely political reasons be scrapped; - that Debits tax be imposed at a flat rate; - that FID and Debits tax be linked together, or alternatively that Debits tax be calculated on an aggregate basis whereby the sum total of each month's transactions are taxed; - that the provisions for short term money market dealers be substantially revised; - that the limit on the maximum Financial Institutions Duty and Debits tax payable be abolished and - that the categories of transactions taxed under the Debits Act be broadened. However, while it can be conceded that political exemptions to these taxes offend the criteria of simplicity and equity, they are politically entrenched so that their abolition is unlikely and would in any event result in only a small revenue increase. Furthermore, while uniformity between the States would be desirable on FID and Debits tax matters, it is unlikely given the poor record on harmonisation of taxation matters between the States in the past. With these reservations in mind we have ventured to propose the following reform of the existing taxes. A FRESH PROPOSAL - A FINANCIAL INSTITUTION TRANSACTION TAX (THE `FIT' TAX) A summary of the features of this proposed tax, which we envisage replacing FID's and Debits tax, follows: - It is a `transaction' tax based on the making of any withdrawals or deposits. - It would be imposed at a flat rate of 0.06%. - It would apply to `accounts' in Western Australia of `financiainstitutions'. The definition of `account' would encompass any interest bearing deposit with a financial institution notwithstanding that financial institution's classification of it. Both cheque, saving, quasi-cheque/saving and term deposit accounts would therefore be caught. The FIT tax would retain the comprehensive definition of `financial institution' that exists within the Financial Institutions Duty Act and also the benchmark requirement of $5 million total dutiable receipts in a year or $416 666 in one month. It is our proposition that any institution receiving less than this amount is not really a commercial organisation and people would be reluctant to switch to them simply to avoid the new FIT tax.[25] - The new FIT tax would retain the provisions in regard to short term money market dealings.[26]- The FIT tax would not impose a ceiling on the maximum amount of tax payable.- The entrenched political exemptions will remain.SimplicityThe FIT tax would therefore retain the simplicity of FID and Debits tax in that there would be few collection points. The new tax would be simpler to understand and calculate. Efficiency The FIT tax would be more efficient than the current taxes as its base is broader and the `ceiling' of maximum tax payable would be removed. The tax also retains the proven `efficient' low tax rate. Equity Due to the broadening of the base, the FIT tax would be more horizontally equitable. The replacement of the regressive Debits rate with a flat tax rate and the abolition of the `ceiling' of a maximum amount of tax payable would also increase the vertical equity of the proposed tax. PROPOSALS FOR THE FUTURE OF FINANCIAL TAXES The Context At present our finances are intimately tied up with banks, be it through cheques issued by the banks or via a visit to the ATMs or even the use of EFTPOS. The future of banking is to have even less bank interaction than at present. Even with our present system it is necessary to have access to the bank for loan applications, credit extensions and other services. In the future all such dealings will be done with the use of a `Smart Card' and `Home Banking'. Smart Cards are like a present card except that they have a microprocessor on the back. This enables the card to store and calculate far more information that can currently be achieved. All purchases will be paid for with this card and all other banking will be done using this card and your personal computer connected to the bank. What does all this have to do with taxation? Its relevance lies in the connection to the bank that is necessary. Different states have different levels of FID and Debit Tax (Queensland has no FID). Despite the savings that could be achieved by locating an account in a different state, at the moment this manoeuvre has the problem of access to the bank. However, the introduction of Smart Cards will mean that people can have an account interstate without any disadvantages. The potential result of this is that the State Government could lose about 10% of its annual revenue.[27]This is where FIT Tax comes into play. It is designed to be a preparatory step towards a tax designed to compensate for the loss of revenue from FID and Debits Tax. Eventually a new tax, Financial Electronic Liability Tax (FELT), would be calculated on the same basis as FIT Tax, a flat rate applied to all debits and credits to the account. However FELT might be applied at the point of sale on the use of the electronic transfer facilities. The Smart Cards themselves could keep track of the tax liability which could then be paid at the end of each period using the home computer. The Constitutional limitations and FELT As is so often the case with State taxes, Constitutional limitations are a relevant concern to the validity of the tax. The first of these potential limitations is based on s.2 of the Australia Act relating to the territorial limitations faced by the states in their taxing activities. This issue is covered best by the Stamp Duty cases of Millar v Commissioner of Stamp Duties (N.S.W.)[28] and Broken Hill South Ltd v Commissioner of Taxation (Qld),[29] which laid down the requirements of connection for a valid tax. They held:...It is also within the competence of the legislature to base the imposition of liability on no more than the relation of the person to the territory. The relation may consist in presence within the territory, residence, domicil, (sic) carrying on business there, or even remoter connections...[30]FELT would be based on the payee residing within the state and also conducting an electronic transfer within the state. It is submitted that this establishes the connection required by the case law. The second limitation is based on s.92 of the Constitution, relating to Freedom of Interstate Trade. This issue arises from the view of taxing people having their money outside W.A., especially when neither the debiting or crediting account is located within W.A. In early cases on the section the free trade aspect was emphasised. In Fox v Robbins,[31] a licensing fee which was lower for hotels selling W.A. beer was held invalid. At later stages however the interpretation changed such that any legislation dealing with interstate trade was viewed as unconstitutional. In W.A. McArthur Ltd v Queensland,[32] a tax which applied equally to both interstate and local goods was held invalid. In the recent case of Cole v Whitfield[33] the free trade aspect of the section was again reinforced. As such, provided there is no disadvantage to interstate trade, which there is not here, because the tax applies equally to people holding accounts in W.A., the tax will be valid. The final issue relates to s.90 of the Constitution and the limitations to the states imposing excises. The purpose of s.90 is arguably to prevent taxes on goods other than those set Federally. The tax does not need to relate to the quality or value of the goods, Matthews v Chicory Marketing Board.[34] Taxes on the production or on the distribution of a good are also an excise, Parton v Milk Board (Vic.).[35] The High Court made it clear that a tax on the final sale to the consumer was an excise in W.A. v Hammersley Iron Pty Ltd[36] and W.A. v Chamberlain Industries Pty Ltd.[37] Both of these cases considered a receipts tax. Under the invalidated legislation, any payment required a receipt to be issued, and duty applied to these receipts. The court declared that a tax on the receipt of the purchase price was a tax on a step of the movement of goods into consumption. It was also held irrelevant whether the tax impacted on goods specifically or incidentally. FELT - A viable option We consider the tax to be distinguishable from the receipts tax on the basis that it is the use of the electronic transfer device that is being taxed not the actual purchase. The tax liability arises on all uses of the device, whether for the repayment of loans, the purchase of services or the acquisition of goods. It is not the purchase of the goods which is being taxed since a payment by way of cash would not attract the tax. In conclusion the face of banking is changing and even if this proposal is not in the final analysis the preferable one, the State government will need to consider options to protect its income base in the face of technological advancement. BIBLIOGRAPHY AUSTRALIAN TAX RESEARCH FOUNDATION, STATE TAXATION: Assessing the New South Wales Tax Force Report, Conference Series No. 9, 1988. [Discusses the proposals put forward by the NSW Task Force - a good overview of tax reform policy.] CARSON, J.B, "A Legislative Review of Section 31B", Stamp Duty Extra Territoriality, Stamp Duty Seminar, 198, Perth. [The paper concentrates on sections 16(3) and 31 B of the Stamp Act 1921 (WA).] CCH 1994 Australian master Tax Guide. [A helpful introduction to Stamp Duty legislation.] FOX B, "Towards the intelligent credit card", New Scientist, v. 121. [Gives a good overview of current banking technology.] LAW SOCIETY OF WESTERN AUSTRALIA, Stamp Duty Legislation in Western Australia, 1983, Park Printing Co., Victoria Park WA. [Good background history to the Stamp Act 1921 (WA).] MUSGRAVE R.A. & MUSGRAVE P.B, Public Finance in Theory and Practice, 5th ed., McGraw-Hill Book Company, 1989. [Helpful introduction to public finance theory principles and taxation.] O'BRYEN, D., "Financial Taxes in Australia", 5 Australian Tax Forum. [Useful background to the taxes.] PEEK, I.G., "Vendors' Difficulties with Unstamped Contracts: Proposals for Reform," 23 Western Australian Law Review 152, 1993. [This article succinctly describes the current problems with s.27(1) of the Stamp Act 1921 (WA) and proposes that it be totally repealed.] PEEK, I.G., "Stamp Duty: The Meaning of "Instrument of Security" In Theory and Practice," 22 Western Australian Law Review 375, 1992. [Discusses the current meaning given to the words "instrument of security" in item 13 of the Second Schedule of the Stamp Act 1921 (WA).] TAXATION POLICY ELECTIVE, 1993 Review of Western Australian State Taxes, Murdoch University: School of Law. [Provided the starting position for taxation policy covered in this chapter.] WESTERN AUSTRALIAN GOVERNMENT WORKING GROUP, Reform of the Stamp Act and Its Administration, (Final Report) 1992. [A very good discussion of various sections within the Act and comprehensive proposals for reform.] WESTERN AUSTRALIAN TAXATION DEPARTMENT, Annual Report 1992-1993, WA State Printer. [Provided figures used.] Notes: [1] Among other things, a "good" tax system should "permit fair and non arbitrary administration and it should be understandable to the taxpayer." R. Musgrave & P. Musgrave, Public Finance in Theory and Practice, 5th Edit. McGraw-Hill Book Company, 1989, p.216. [2] Australian Master Tax Guide, CCH para. 37-000. [3] Reform of the Stamp Act and its Administration. Final Report of the Western Australian Government Working Group, July 1992 (hereafter "The Final Report"), p.v. [4] Tax Policy Elective, 1993 Review of Western Australian State Taxes, Murdoch University 1993, Chapter 3 `Stamp Duty', pp.36-53 at p.41. But note, the 1993 Tax Policy Elective group referred to horizontal equity, that is, that people with equal capacity should pay the same, whereas a better description would be that its application is inequitable because "each taxpayer should contribute his or her fair share to the cost of government". See supra, n. 1 at p. 218. [5] Id p.41. [6] Id. p.45. [7] Id. p.46., and The Final Report, supra, n. 3 at p.x. [8] Western Australian State Taxation Department, Annual Report, p.23 Financial Statements for Year Ended 30 June 1993. Stamp Duty revenue was $432,156,132, which is approximately 35% of Consolidated Revenue Fund Receipts. [9] The 1993 Tax Policy Elective Review alluded to this, see supra, n. 4 at pp.41, 48. [10] Report of Australian Payment System Council 1991-92, p.26. [11] As per discussion with representatives at the W.A. State Taxation Department. Also note, this was an area of the Stamp Act that the 1993 Tax Policy Elective group considered should be abolished - instead it is being up-dated for an new era. [12] See Re Exbea Pty Ltd; Ex parte M & W Holdings Pty Ltd (1989) 1 WAR 287; Re Odin Inns Pty Ltd; Ex parte Greenpark Pty Ltd 89 ATC 4931; and more recently, Ioannou v Silver Royal Pty Ltd (1993) State Reports (Western Australia) 9 Part 4 at 200. [13] See ss.74(1), 39(1) and item 4(1) of the Second Schedule to the Act. [14] See I G Peek, "Vendors' Difficulties with Unstamped Contracts: Proposals for Reform", Western Australian Law Review 23, p.153. [15] Stamp Duty Legislation in Western Australia, The Law Society of Western Australia, 1983, pp. 4, 5. [16] See ss. 20(1), 39 generally, and 39A; also I G Peek supra, n.14 at p.155; and The Law Society, Id. p.6. [17] See The Final Report, supra, n. 3 at p.ix. [18] Section 29(4) of the Stamp Duties Act 1920 (NSW); Section 28(2) of the Stamp Duties Act 1931 (Tas), cited in I G Peek, supra, n. 14 at p.155. [19] Public Finance in Theory and Practice, supra, n. 1 at p.216; See also The Final Report, where it was submitted that there was a need for a manual detailing procedures and explanations of the Act in layman's language, supra, n.3 at p. 92. [20] Section 10 of the FID Act.A Financial Institution must register under s.22 of the FID Act if its total dutiable receipts in the previous year exceeded $5 million or $416 666 during the preceding month. [21] An `unregistered financial institution' is one that must register under s.22 but has not. Last year's review noted that s.12 is an anti-avoidance provision that has not been resorted to thus far, supra, n.4 at p.55. [22] Supra n 8. [23] Definition of "account"; (a) kept with banks, from which cheques can be drawn upon (i.e commonly referred to as cheque account) or (b) kept with non-bank financial institutions from which payment orders can be drawn upon." [24] See, Chapter 4 `Financial Institutions Duty and Debits Tax', supra, n.4 at p.67. [25] Depositors may weigh the benefit of avoiding this relatively small tax with the riskiness of banking with smaller financial institutions, particularly since recent spectacular crashes of smaller financial institutions eg. Teachers Credit Society and Western Women. [26] Supra, n. 7. [27] Supra, n.8. [28] (1932) 48 CLR 618. [29] (1937) 56 CLR 337. [30] Id. at p.375 per Dixon J. [31] (1909) 9 CLR 115. [32] (1920) 28 CLR 530. [33] (1988) 78 ALR 42. [34] (1938) 60 CLR 263. [35] (1949) 80 CLR 229. [36] (1969) 120 CLR 42. [37] (1970) 121 CLR 201.