E LAW - MURDOCH UNIVERSITY ELECTRONIC JOURNAL OF LAW VOLUME 1 NUMBER 4 (DECEMBER 1994) Copyright E Law and/or authors Review of Western Australian State Taxes 1994 Chapter 8 REVIEW OF LOCAL GOVERNMENT TAXATION Introduction The Functions of Local Government The Changing Face of Local Government Land Value Rating as Taxation The Rating System Rating and Equity Finding Alternatives The Personal Element The UK Experience Conclusion Bibliography INTRODUCTION The existing pattern of local government taxation in Australia reflects the limited responsibilities assigned to local authorities by the States. Local government's role has traditionally been described in terms of the three Rs: rates, roads and rubbish. Ignored as a government level in its own right in the Commonwealth Constitution, local government has been established by virtue of State legislation such as the Local Government Act 1960-1982 (LGA) in Western Australia. In 1991-92, local councils in Western Australia raised only 43.5% of what was required for their own purpose outlays from the single tax base of property rates.[1] As a result, the revenue raising capacity of local government has been criticised as being unduly narrow and restrictive. The question of how local government might improve the efficiency of its current tax base, widen its taxation powers, and whether a move towards alternative forms of revenue raising can be justified forms the basis of this chapter. The Functions of Local Government The three Rs fail to accurately describe the role of local government in modern society and the diversity of services it provides. Local government in Australia was originally set up to provide services to real property, mainly in the forms of roads, bridges, and garbage collection and disposal. Nowadays, however, local government services extend to the regulation of building, to town and environmental planning, public order and safety, and the provision of cultural, recreational, educational, welfare and health amenities.[2] According to conventional fiscal federalism theory, services associated with social security, health, and public order are the very type that local government should be providing.[3] Over the past ten years, the underlying aim of personal welfare services has undergone a fundamental change from curing to prevention, and from maintenance to development. Consequently, these services are understood now as being an integral part of local community development.[4] The Changing Face of Local Government Local government expenditure on social welfare services has increased from 4.5% in 1982 to 6.6% in 1991-92.[5] The increase is attributed to two main factors. The resurgence in interest in local government activities by the federal government, and amendments to the LGA.First of all, local government has been regarded by the Commonwealth since the early 1980s as a community-based organisation eligible to make submissions for funds under various health, welfare and recreational programs.[6] This policy provides a mechanism whereby the federal government can bypass the States in devolving funds directly to the community. Secondly, amendments to the LGA have empowered local authorities to appropriate moneys out of their municipal funds towards the provision of counselling, refuge services, and child and youth care.[7] Thus, local government's role has broadened along with its financial commitment. The same cannot be said of its revenue-raising capacities. Aside from rates levied on property, other sources of local government revenue include local fines and fees, enterprise income, interest, borrowing and net movements in investments, cash and securities, and grants from other levels of government.[8] However, many of these revenue sources are limited in both scope and capacity for further exploitation by local government. For example, local government trading enterprises are typically confined to providing goods and services such as caravan parks and quarries, which are not favoured by private enterprise and which return limited profits.[9]The Commonwealth contribution to local government commenced with the enactment of the Commonwealth Grants Commission Act 1973 and payment was in the form of a specified proportion of personal income tax revenue. This changed in 1986 with the passing of the Local Government (Financial Assistance) Act 1986 (Cth) which provides for untied financial assistance grants via the States to local government. Since the introduction of financial assistance grants, however, the annual federal budget allocation to local government as a percentage of personal income tax has actually fallen from 2% in 1985-86 to 1.32% in 1988-89.[10] Declining financial support from other governments is but one of the reasons why local government must increasingly rely upon its own abilities to raise revenue, and more specifically, upon property rates.The historical reliance on property by local government as a means of raising revenue was seen as appropriate. The ownership of property and land reflected to a marked degree a person's wealth. Moreover, moneys raised from property-based revenue were primarily channelled back into the maintenance and provision of such property. Representation on local government, therefore, was directly linked with the ownership of property.[11] However, local government tax revenues from municipal rates have not kept pace with economic growth indicated by gross domestic product (GDP). State government land tax yields have increased significantly as a share of GDP from 1.8% in 1950 to 5% in 1990. Municipal rate revenues, however, have declined from 1% to .9% as a share of GDP over the same period.[12]The decline in tax yields suggests that local government needs to access a tax base with growth potential. At the same time, it reveals a reluctance on the part of councils in general to increase the amount of revenue they derive from property tax. Not only is the ability to increase revenue from rates constrained by taxation policies of State and federal government,[13] but rates constitute an unpopular form of taxation, aggravated by high visibility in the annual rate bill. Local government authorities are understandably reluctant to further exploit property tax as a means of meeting their financial commitments.[14] Sources of Local Government Revenue Taxation on property values is referred to as a `rate' in the LGA. If the classical definition of what constitutes a tax is examined, however, rates fit squarely within its parameters. Rates are the compulsory exaction of money by a public authority for public purposes, enforceable by law. They are not payments for services rendered.[15]In practice, the distinction between a tax and a rate would be of little consequence except for the fact that many ratepayers do not perceive property rates as a tax. This perception is perpetuated by the seeming nexus between rates paid and the benefits received. As has been pointed out, moneys raised from property rates in Australia have historically been channelled back into property one way or another. So garbage collection and disposal, for example, is a service provided to property owners through the payment of rates. In this sense, rates are regarded by the public as a payment for services rendered. However, not all local government services are provided individually to ratepayers, nor do they provide benefits to all ratepayers.[16]The majority of taxes are unrequited, which makes it is difficult for a taxpayer to make a connection between the tax paid on X and any benefit received. Local government itself perceives the local rate on property as being distinct from your average `Sheriff of Nottingham take from the poor and give to the rich' tax. However, as local government expenditure on services unrelated to property increases, the local rate on property becomes less requited and more in the nature of a classical tax. Having discussed the basic machinery of local government taxation in Western Australia, we will now assess the local rate on property values in terms of equity, efficiency and simplicity. Land value rating as a form of taxation: the two sides of equity, efficiency and simplicity.[17] EQUITY Advantages Approximate benefit derived A tax should be fair in relation to the benefit a taxpayer receives from the expenditure of the tax. Property rates can be justified on the basis that local government funding is primarily devoted to providing services that have a high relationship to property. Cultural recreation amenities also provide an indirect benefit to property owners by making their area more attractive. Approximate capacity to pay According to the notion of vertical equity, a tax should be borne more heavily by those with a greater capacity to pay. Arguably, it is those people with a greater overall wealth who own the most valuable properties. The calculation of rates on the basis of land values therefore will mean those people with the greatest capacity to pay will be paying the most rates. Approximate use of a tax base Along with State land tax, local government rates are one of the few taxes on assets as opposed to income; some proportion of taxation of assets is appropriate if people are to be taxed according to their capacity to pay. Objectivity The use of land values provided by a State government department means that an objective measure is used to determine the basis for rates. This in turn encourages cross jurisdictional equity amongst ratepayers by eliminating the risk of individual councils distorting land values for their own revenue-raising purpose. Disadvantages Unsatisfactory match with benefit received Whilst property owners are taxed, other members of the local community who also derive a benefit from the council's activities may not be taxed, ie. non-ratepayers who utilise parklands or libraries within the municipality. The property owner is virtually called upon to finance all local-government activities, irrespective of the nature and extent of the service given. Unsatisfactory match with capacity to pay In order to achieve vertical equity, there needs to be a correlation between the higher rates of the tax and the ability of the taxpayer to pay the tax. However, wealth can be held in many forms other than land, and as such it cannot be said that this correlation necessarily exists. Land values have no regard to the owners debt position or low of income. Tax on assets causes hardship A tax on assets, especially on such a common asset as land, is harsh on those people who may be income poor and asset rich (such as retired people). Inequities, measured by capacity to pay, occur where certain areas are subject to escalation of property values not matched by increases in real income levels. Local government discretion The rate set by local government is ultimately determined on the arbitrary basis of the income it requires to finance expenditure. Ratepayers in different municipalities can therefore expect to pay rates according to the revenue-raising needs of their respective councils. In this sense, objective land values are only illusory. EFFICIENCY Advantages Immobility of the tax base The lack of mobility of the tax base (land) makes property rates a suitable tax for small, local jurisdictions. Because of the immobility of the tax base, property owners will not be liable to shift geographically in response to differences in tax rates between localities. Revenue potential Land value taxation is economically efficient in that it is broadly based and yields significant revenue for local government. Revenue predictability The revenue yields of land value taxation are generally of a readily predictable amount. This enables both local government and property owners to arrange their finances and resources with some certainty. Property ownership discouraged It is arguable that people will choose to invest their moneys in assets less heavily taxed than land. Property rates, along with land tax and stamp duty, impose a heavy tax burden on property owners. Even if people do decide to invest their moneys in land, they may be more inclined to do so in a local government area which traditionally charges low rates, or which applies the differential rating system. The statistics Statistics indicate that whilst local rates raise significant revenue, they also exhibit the least buoyant revenue yields in comparison to real revenue yields of stamp duty and land tax. Furthermore, as numerous properties are exempt from rating under the Local Government Act, the full revenue-raising capacity of local government is not realised. Unpredictable revenue yields Land values may be unpredictable from year to year, particularly in rural areas where fluctuating weather conditions and macro-economic factors impact heavily on the value of income-earning land. SIMPLICITY Advantages Avoidance is difficult and the tax simple Because ownership of land is regulated by the State, avoidance of rates is effectively impossible. The tax is readily recouped in the event that rates are not paid; land, being immobile, is easily claimed by authorities. This, combined with the fact that a tax on land value is simply calculated, means that administration costs are far less than for forms of taxation where collection and enforcement would be more difficult. Increasing complexity of the tax and use of resources Valuation is not as simple as it may initially appear. The introduction of differential forms of rating, exemptions from property valuation, dual systems of rating, deferred payment of rates, discounts and rebate schemes means that the tax is both complicated and made difficult to administer. Furthermore, the process of valuation involves significant use of resources, thus expenditure is necessary for the provision of regularly updated valuation of properties. As demonstrated, raising revenue by means of property rating has identifiable advantages and disadvantages. Moreover, inferences can be drawn with regard to issues of equity, efficiency and simplicity. Whilst it is apparent that amounts raised are insufficient to meet expenditure, the system is efficient because it still raises significant revenue and remains simple to administer. The question of whether property rates operate equitably, however, is more problematic. An examination of the rating system provides a better understanding of property tax with respect to equity. The Rating System The rating system is contained in two pieces of legislation, the LGA and the Valuation of Land Act 1978 (VLA). Rating is based on the property valuation of rateable land which is conducted independently of local government by the State valuer-general's department. Section 532 of the LGA defines all land as rateable, except that which is exempted. Exemptions include: 1. Crown land used for a public purpose or which is unoccupied or vested under the Parks and Reserves Act or is used for horticultural shows or recreational purposes. 2. Land belonging to a religious body used or held as a place of public worship. 3. Land used exclusively as a public hospital, school (both public and private), library, museum. 4. Land used for charitable purposes. The owner-occupied residence is not exempt. The rating system applies to owners of residences as well as to owners of land used for commercial purposes. The formula used for calculating property tax appears reasonably simple. Each local council determines how much money it needs to raise, subtracts the revenue expected from other sources such as general purpose grants, fees, fines, and so on, and then divides that by the total property valuations of the local government area.[18] Case in Point The City of Bunbury has calculated the following rate for the 1993-94 financial year:[19] Total valuation of properties $ 82,000,000 total revenue required $ 23,000,000 revenue from other sources - $ 17,200,000 requires rate revenue $ 5,800,000 $82,000,000 divided by $5,800,000 = 7 Therefore, the rate set by Council = $ .07 per $1.00 Examples 1. Ms Smith's property, based on a GRV[20] of $10,000, will yield .07 x 10,000 = $700. 2. Ms Jones' property has a GRV OF $25,000. She will pay .07 x 25,000 = $1,750. Family circumstances in the above examples may be entirely different. Ms Jones may be a single person without dependants, on a high income and debt-free, whilst Ms Smith may be a single parent with two dependant children, on a moderate income and with a mortgage. Whilst the rate is assessed on the ad valorem value of the property, they will both pay the same rate in the dollar, regardless of their cash flow or their household income. Two valuation systems are available to local government under the LGA. Gross rental value (GRV) is the annual rental that a property could be expected to realise and is generally applied to urban land. Unimproved value (UIV), which is the system used by shire councils in rural areas, refers to the amount that a property could be expected to realise upon its sale without taking into account the value of any improvements.[21] Many councils operate dual systems. The GRV system recognises the income-earning potential of a property and is therefore appropriate from a revenue raising perspective. Further, as developed urban properties tend to use council services to varying degrees, the GRV system taxes more heavily those property owners who get most benefit from council. For example, a single residence located in proximity to a high rise block of units would have a similar unimproved value as the entire block of units. But the application of GRV redresses this distortion. It ensures that the rate burden falls more heavily on the owner of the high rise units, the tenants of which collectively use more services than the residential property owner. By applying differential rates based on different land zoning, local authorities can go even further to correct possible inequities in the sharing of the rate burden. Differential rates recognise that commercial and industrial properties have greater earning capacities than residential land.[22] This device also provides for specified area rates whereby certain properties are likely to enjoy particular benefits, such as a sewerage scheme, from council. Councils are permitted to set minimum rates to ensure that all rateable properties make a reasonable contribution irrespective of their valuation.[23] Certain restrictions apply to minimum rates, however. A council is not permitted to use the minimum rate as a device to effect a flat charge per property and thus replace the ad valorem system which recognises that those with higher property values pay higher rates. In acknowledgment of the potential hardship to pensioners who may asset-rich but income-poor, the State government, under the Rates and Charges (Rebates and Deferments) Act 1992 provides for rates concessions in two ways: the 50% rebate, which is reimbursed to local council, and payment deferment. The latter allows for payment of rates to be deferred until such time as the property is settled, with the State government paying interest on the deferred monies. The significance of this is that pensioners are relieved of the burden of paying rates until they dispose of the property. The rate schedule imposed by the City of Bunbury is more complicated than it would appear at first glance. The minimum rate is $275.00 per residential property per year. Seven cents in the dollar translates to: 1. Residential zone: 6.49 cents; 2. Commercial zone: 6.85 cents; 3. Specified Area Rate (to provide parking in the Central Business District): 0.42 cents. Rate variation indicates the flexibility provided by the LGA for councils to determine their own financial needs. It also suggests the potential for large discrepancies between councils in the application of the rating system. Rating and Equity A council's ability to shift the tax burden from one set of ratepayers to another purportedly achieves equity. However, in many respects, the tax is not equitable and would appear to be unfairly imposed on constituents who have least ability to pay. As was explained earlier, the property tax makes no distinction between the income-earning capacity of Ms Smith and Ms Jones. During the late 1980s councils became concerned that the ability to pay rates did not necessarily equate with property value. A study of forty-four collector districts in Western Australia in 1989 confirmed that there is no strict correlation between high property values and high income, and that there are some areas which have proportionally high property values but lower incomes.[24] Studies also indicate that rates, as a percentage of household disposable income, decline as a person's income capacity increases.[25] This is in contrast to a progressive tax system where the more a person earns, the more she pays. With a property tax, then, the more a person earns, the less she pays in proportion to her income. If regressivity occurs where the incidence of the tax falls more heavily on people with low incomes, property tax is potentially regressive because it does not take into account a household's disposable income.Local authorities exercise discretion to shift the burden amongst ratepayers by rating business and commercial property owners higher than residential property owners. This purportedly achieves equity. However it can be argued that the tax burden is shifted onto consumers of council goods and services, many of whom are non-property owners with less ability to pay. The incidence of burden shifting is largely hidden, however, and the community has no way of identifying the role that rates play in the structure of prices.[26] The position of landlord and tenant illustrates this point. A landlord can transfer the rate burden to the tenant in the form of rental costs. As rates on business can be legitimately claimed against income tax, the general taxpayer, including the non-property owner, compensates for the revenue foregone. The value of the transfer can be of great financial significance to the commercial property owner, who is likely to be paying a higher marginal tax rate.[27] Thus, because commercial ratepayers are able to shift the rates burden onto consumers, the differential rating system does not necessarily achieve equity.[28] The system is even more unfair to pensioner tenants because rebate schemes are available only to property owners.[29] Finding Alternatives To summarise, property taxation raises inadequate revenue and does not distribute the taxation burden in an equitable manner. The purpose of reform, then, should be to increase the potential for revenue raising, and to bring about equity. Reform options which will now be examined focus on the inclusion of a personal taxation element. These take the form of an income tax and a poll tax. The Personal Element The imposition of devices which have been developed overseas for personal taxation are poll tax and local income tax. Poll tax can be described as a flat rate levied upon every member of the community who is on the electoral roll.[30] In WA, any person over eighteen years who owns or occupies a rateable property is eligible to vote in local elections whether or not they hold Australian citizenship.[31] This group would be the likely target for a poll tax. Advocates claim that poll tax would be fairer than property tax alone because: 1. All who benefit from council expenditure are liable to contribute.2. Services provided by local government are related more to personal needs than to property.3. The rating of land disadvantages those whose properties are valued at a high level on account of factors not specifically related to local government services.4. All people in the council area have a right to benefits, not just property owners. 5. Since all voting adults are liable, the tax becomes more visible and this in turn makes local government more accountable.[32] Detractors, on the other hand, point out that with a poll tax: 1. There is no regard for personal circumstances, capacity to pay or the value of one's assets or income.2. Implementation and collection of revenue is difficult.3. The fact that local government services are still predominantly property related is ignored.4. Such fundamental change leads to widespread anxiety and concern. 5. It is necessary to implement two systems since poll tax is not appropriate for non-domestic properties. 6. Administrative costs are prohibitive.[33]Poll tax has not been imposed in Australia, except in Victoria.[34] Historically it was perceived that complications in collection would arise due to the large migrant and transient populations.[35] Recently, however, the United Kingdom experience sheds light on other difficulties. The UK Experience Poll tax was imposed with disastrous effect in the late 1980s and has been blamed for the downfall of Margaret Thatcher and for upsetting an already fragile sense of social cohesion.[36] Strathclyde Council, for example, spent sixteen million pounds setting up the infrastructure for collection,[37] and in the end, non-compliance and enforcement cost most councils ten percent of the amount collected.[38] Unforeseen legal problems also resulted from the tax. Defaulters were struck off the electoral roll, and thus disenfranchised; council authorities issued summonses daily in their thousands to defaulters; non-payment, while a civil offence, was covered by criminal provisions in the Act and civil procedure broke down as millions of defaulters clogged the courts, with cases backlogged for years; magistrates resigned claiming they were forced into acting as tax collectors and the courts were being made a laughing stock as defendants made political speeches and disrupted proceedings.[39] Poll tax quickly gave way and modified schemes took over.[40] These schemes redefined rateable assessment, merging the personal and property elements. A model was imposed which was a flat rate based on a two-adult household, with exemptions for singles, and a percentage of the property's capital value was added. Problems arose in establishing a reliable method to verify the existence of a single adult household. Furthermore, many properties had greatly appreciated in value over the years while their owners' incomes did not keep pace. The rate could vary greatly between councils depending upon the level of the council's expenditure.[41] It is clear that poll tax was a failure, presenting great difficulties in collection, and that property rates had to be reintroduced in an attempt to provide a more reliable base.A second option, personal income taxation, will now be examined. Income tax surcharges on behalf of local government have been dismissed by some analysts as inappropriate. They cite the following reasons: 1. Local government authorities do not possess the legal power to impose an income tax or to ask the Commonwealth to impose or collect such a tax on their behalf. 2. State governments would be unlikely to grant local government such powers or to request on their behalf that the Commonwealth levy such a tax. 3. The Commonwealth is precluded by s99 of the Constitution from differentiating between States or parts of States in the imposition of taxes so that any surcharge would have to be uniform throughout Australia unless the Commonwealth acted merely as collecting agent.[42] However, other analysts do not acknowledge the veracity of all these arguments and hold that:1. The surcharge could be assesed and collected locally, or assessed locally and collected by the Commonwealth. 2. Alternatively, local income tax could indeed be set uniformly at either national or state level and collected by the Commonwealth.[43] An alternative to taxing the individual would be to tax household income utilising the national census data collected every five years by the Australian Bureau of Statistics. However, household income varies with factors such as family size, stage of the life cycle, labour force participation, and geographical location.[44] The fact that people's circumstances change more frequently than property values means that five-yearly assessment would unreliable. The cost of continuous assessment would be beyond the resources of local government, and the Commonwealth would be hard pressed to conduct a yearly census having regard to the enormity of expense and resources involved. CONCLUSION The abandonment of the property element cannot be contemplated as a viable option. To reiterate, the property base is reliable, raises significant revenue, and the public is used to it. The advantages of maintaining the property rating system far outweigh the disadvantages in terms of efficiency and simplicity. If the system of rating property were abandoned in favour of a personal tax base to bring about equity, then efficiency and simplicity would be lost due to more complex assessment, collection and enforcement procedures. Notwithstanding the obvious benefits of raising large amounts of revenue by imposing a local income tax, it is submitted that the notion is impractical in Australia. Since the Commonwealth has effectively removed income taxation power from the States, it is most unlikely to devolve it to local government. BIBLIOGRAPHY ADVISORY COUNCIL FOR INTER-GOVERNMENT RELATIONS, Discussion Paper 4, `Additional Revenue Sources for Local Government, 1981, ACIR, Hobart. [An overview of local government in 1981.] ADVISORY COUNCIL FOR INTER-GOVERNMENT RELATIONS, Report 7, `Responsibilities and Resouces of Australian Local Government, 1984, AGPS. [Canvases ways and means of raising funds.] AISBETT, ALAN AND JULIE LOMAS. `Council, Son of Poll Tax', Solicitors Journal vol 135 no 20, 24 May 1992, p630. [update on recent revision of local government taxation in UK.] AUSTRALIAN URBAN AND REGIONAL DEVELOPMENT REVIEW, Discussion Paper No 1. [Examines issues of capacity to pay local government rates.] CITY OF BUNBURY 1993-94 Financial Year Budgets. [Useful analyses and tables.] Councillors' Manual (Supplied by the Country Shire Councils Association of WA Inc), 1988, Department of Local Government. [Excellent source of procedures and explanations of rating system.] `Debating the Rating' Local government Bulletin vol 44, no 5, June 1989, p2. [Brief discussion.] EVATT RESEARCH CENTRE Breach of Contract: Privatisation and the Management of Australian Local Government, Leichhardt NSW: Pluto Press 1991. [Good source of information about duties and responsibilities; historical information.] LOCAL GOVERNMENT ASSOCIATION OF WESTERN AUSTRALIA, `Assessing Capacity to Pay Local Government Rates' special conference minutes, Perth 1989. [Text of papers presented by councillors, etc.] `Local Government Revenue Raising Capacity' National Institute of Economic and Industry Research, Melbourne (no date). MOWBRAY, MARTIN, `Rates, Roads, Rubbish & Redistribution: the Politics of Local Taxation' Journal of Australian Political Economy vol 11, Jan 1982 p73. [Comparative analysis; informative.] NATIONAL INSTITUTE OF ECONOMIC AND INDUSTRY RESEARCH `Local Government Revenue Raising Capacity' discussion paper, Melbourne (no date). OAKES, NORMAN (chairperson), Report of Committee of Inquiry into Local Government Rating and Other Revenue Powers and Resource, April 1990, Sydney. REES, KATHRYN, `The State Deficit Levy Act' Law Institute Journal vol 67, April 1993, p272. [Analysis of Victorian `poll' tax.] `Taxation Choices for Community Value: conference proceedings' Australian Municipal Journal vol 71 no 1051, August 1991, p11. THOMAS, G. `From McKenzie Friend to Leicester Assistant: the impact of the poll tax' [1992] Public Law 208. [Discussion of revenue raising and the impact of poll tax upon the legal system in the UK.] THOMSON, NORMAN, `The revenue raising capacity of local government: the ratepayers or their property?' The Australian Quarterley vol 53-54, Spring 1981, p343. [Informative.] `UK Looks to Poll Tax' Local Government Journal vol 15, no 3, 1989, p25. [Foreshadows negative impact of the scheme.] WESTERN AUSTRALIAN MUNICIPAL ASSOCIATION `Taxation Reforms: Choices for Local Government' discussion paper, Perth 1991. Notes: [1] Australian Urban and Regional Development Review Discussion Paper No.1, p 3. [2] Evatt Research Centre, Breach of Contract: Privatisation and the Management of Australian Local Government, Pluto Press, Leichhardt NSW, 1990, p 15. [3] supra n2 p 27. [4] Advisory Council for Inter-governmental Relations, Report 7 Responsibilities and Resources of Australian Local Government, 1984, p 37. [5] supra n1 p 3. [6] G.A.Wood, `How do Australian State and Local Governments Tax Residential Housing?', Australian Tax Forum, v.9, 1992, p 14. [7] s.446 Local Government Act 1960-82 (WA). [8] Oakes, N. Report of Committee of Inquiry into Local Government Rating and other Revenue Powers and Resources April 1990, p 5. [9] The National Institute of Economic and Industry Research, Local Government Revenue Raising Capacity, Melbourne (no date), p 82. [10] supra n2 p 58. [11] supra n3 p 12. [12] Western Australian Municipal Association, Taxation Reform: Choices for Local Government discussion paper, Perth 1991, p 3. [13] supra n3 p 8. [14] Ibid p 36. [15] Matthews v Chicory Marketing Board (1938) 60 CLR 263, per Latham CJ at 270. [16] Air Caledonie International v Commonwealth (1988) 82 ALR 385, per the Court at 391. [17] supra n3, p 34-36. [18] Councillors Manual (Supplied by the Country Shire Councils' Association of W.A. Inc.) Dept. of Local Government, 1988. Appendix: `The Local Government Rating System', p 2. [19] City of Bunbury 1993-94 Financial Year Budgets p 47. Figures approximate. [20] Gross Rental Value. [21] Valuation of Land Act 1978 (WA) s4. [22] LGA s548(4)(b). [23] LGA s552. [24] Local Government Association of Western Australia, Special Conference 1989 Assessing Capacity To Pay Local Government Rates, Minutes, pp 16-26. [25] Mowbray M, `Rates, Rubbish & Redistribution: the Politics of Local Taxation', Journal of Australian Political Economy , 11 January 1982, p 80. [26] supra n3 p 33. [27] supra n27 p 77. [28] supra n3 p 31. [29] supra n27 p 83. [30] supra n18 p 19. [31] LGA s35. [32] supra n3 p 73; n18 p 19-23. [33] ibid. [34] The State Deficit Levy Act 1992 (Vic) is not actually a device for raising local government revenue; it is a $100 a year levy imposed on each Victorian ratepayer to raise revenue of $180 million a year. For efficiency's sake, the levy is collected by local government, but the money is handed over to the state for consolidated revenue. The question remains whether local councils in Victoria will drop the levy or collect it on behalf of themselves should the Victorian government ever decide to repeal the Act. [35] supra n18 p 19. [36] G Thomas, `From McKenzie Friend to Leicester Assistant: the impact of the poll tax' [1992] Public Law p 208. [37] 'UK Looks to Poll Tax', Local Government Journal vol 15, no 3, 1989 p 25. [38] A. Aisbett and J. Lomas, `Council, son of Poll Tax', Solicitors Journal vol 135 no 20, 24 May 1992, p 630. [39] supra n37. [40] supra n39. [41] ibid. [42] supra n11 p 69. [43] supra n3 p 78. [44] supra n25 p 25.